What Is Transaction Cost Economics?
Transaction cost economics is the study of when certain activities of a corporation should be performed internally versus when it makes sense for the firm to delegate such operations to third parties through the use of contracts. Transaction cost economics is a branch of economics that studies the economics of transactions, as well as their costs and benefits.
The definition and historical context are as follows:
The theoretical foundations of Transaction Cost Economics can be traced back to the early twentieth-century writings of Ronald Coase (1937, 1960) on the costs of market transactions and Alchian and Demsetz (1972) on their information cost model. Transaction Cost Economics is the study of the costs of market transactions.
Coase raised the question of whether certain operations should be performed internally by the organization or whether it is preferable for the organization to provide the necessary support for the market to perform the aforementioned operations (i.e. through contracts). The foundation of neoclassical economics is a discussion of how one can benefit from the ‘direct exchange’ that occurs between productivity and rewards in a market environment, which is the foundation of the corporation.
Building a business necessitates the internalization of a trade, which can only be accomplished with a thorough understanding of the manufacturing process, as well as the ability to monitor and track it, as well as the ability to offer incentives and penalties to employees. When all input (capital and labor) owners collaborate in the presence of a central “contractual party,” this is referred to as having an integrated exchange or having a corporation.
Alchian and Demsetz (1972) contributed to the discussion by claiming that information on the performance of people’s labor effort is always a monitoring cost for any organization, regardless of size. Labor is used as an input in a contractual employment relationship, which necessitates the act of monitoring against shirking when the labor process is ambiguous in any way in order to maintain the employment relationship.
This function can be performed at each level of a hierarchy by a single person with specific skills (for example, a supervisor or manager), which reduces monitoring costs. To compensate the central contracting party, which serves as the firm’s performance monitor, the firm’s owners should have the authority to change contracts and incentives as needed.
High metering difficulties, according to Alchian and Demsetz, occur when the effective flow of information on individual performance is reduced or impeded, as is the case with large teams or unsupervised professionals, resulting in the development of organizational inefficiencies. There are exceptions to this rule; however, the rule is broken if the labor force is so small that individuals’ individually chosen profit-sharing incentivizes them to self-monitor their own performance. Partnerships in a law firm, for example, would be an exception to this rule.
Mr. Oliver E. Williamson, who is now known as Transaction Cost Economics, developed Coase and Alchian’s work into a theory of Transaction Cost Economics (1975, 1981, 1988, 1993, and 1996). Organizational structures incur information costs, whereas employees intentionally conceal information about their job performance incur “transaction costs.” This is most common when employees have highly specialized abilities or gain significant knowledge during the course of their careers.
Working conditions have improved as a result, according to Williamson, and workers now have more control over the labor process’s efficiency. Frederick Taylor’s concepts of natural soldiering and systematic soldiering are strikingly similar to this concept of soldiering (Luhman, 2005: 149). According to neoclassical economics, human nature is utilitarian, and as a result, when given the opportunity to do so without being caught, all workers will naturally shirk from their tasks. Corporations must monitor individual performance, which necessitates the establishment of hierarchical control systems as well as, perhaps, more importantly, labor divisions within their organizations.
Another option for a company is to establish market relationships with people who do jobs or provide services that are equivalent to those provided by the firm. To ensure that this is met, internal activities are typically outsourced. Transaction cost economics is an economic theory that holds that as manufacturing operations are moved out of the business and into the market, efficiency will automatically increase for all of the actors involved.
Scholars and theorists have made the following observations:
Laffont and Martimort (1998) conducted a theoretical examination of the transaction costs that occur between government regulators and the regulated interest groups. This was one of the first applications of transaction cost economics in the field of organizational and management studies, and it was published in the journal Organizational and Management Studies. The authors compared the costs and benefits of the government establishing a large number of specialized regulatory agencies versus the costs and benefits of the government establishing a single centralized regulatory body to manage an entire industry in their study.
They claimed that the existence of numerous specialized agencies raises the costs borne by interest groups because they must influence a larger number of organizations rather than a single centralized organization. As a result, an interest group’s ability to overcome or mitigate the consequences of government regulation and oversight is reduced. It goes without saying that this is in the best interests of a society that wants to impose those regulations on the industry in the first place. The only way for interest groups to reduce their costs is to increase the effectiveness of their lobbying efforts (for example, by the use of industry-wide lobbying fronts).
Vázquez (2004) investigates decision-making rights in unionized food and electronic industries in a second application. When it came to allocating decision rights, he discovered that employer opportunism had a stronger explanatory power than employee opportunism.
Management defines employee choice rights as the option of holding decision-making power in their own hands or delegating decision-making power downward to subordinates and subordinates. The investigation was conducted in Spain during a period of high unemployment, and the author came to the conclusion that employers used their relative strength to centralize rather than decentralize decision-making.
Although transaction cost economics is theoretically sound, Tsang (2006) contends that the model is flawed because it is based on several important behavioral assumptions, including bounded rationality (we cannot know everything), opportunism (human nature is self-seeking), risk neutrality (human nature is also adverse to failure), and cost minimization (human nature is also adverse to failure) (human nature always limits individual costs in relation to individual benefits).
Transaction cost economics is based on behavioral assumptions, which suggests that economic governance should shift away from corporations (where transaction costs are high) and toward direct market trade (where there are low transaction costs). Tsang, on the other hand, claims that the underlying behavioral premise of opportunism has never been empirically tested in a systematic manner. In terms of efficiency, a corporation’s ability to create and transfer knowledge among its members distinguishes it from the rest of the market.
Sources: